Agenda Advancing economics in business Shades of grey: arguments for and against parallel trade in pharmaceuticals Last month the European Court of Justice announced its judgment on Syfait v GlaxoSmithKline, the latest case concerning parallel trading (aka grey imports). One of the most pressing competition issues facing the pharmaceutical industry, this topic was discussed during the second Oxera Economics Council meeting that took place in Brussels on September 15th
Parallel trade in pharmaceuticals in the EU was worth
Actions taken by pharmaceutical companies to limit
approximately €4.3 billion in 2006.1 Parallel importers
parallel trading are currently being investigated in a
buy medicines under patent in Member States where
number of competition cases, most prominently where
wholesale prices are relatively low, and sell them at a
pharmaceutical companies have refused to supply to
higher price in other Member States—a form of
parallel importers. September’s judgement of the
international arbitrage. In other words, parallel traders
European Court of Justice (ECJ) in the Syfait v
find it profitable to re-package and export pharmaceutical
GlaxoSmithKline case is one of the most recent
products after they have been sold to a wholesaler by
examples (see the box below). These cases raise
the manufacturer. Because a guiding principle of the EU
economic questions regarding the underlying rationale
is the single internal market, parallel traders do not
for implementing strategies designed to limit parallel
require permission from the patent holders to export in
this way. As parallel importing tends to reduce therevenues earned by branded pharmaceutical companies,
This article focuses on three main questions which are
there are incentives for these companies to attempt to
important for understanding parallel importing, and where
limit the amount of parallel trade occurring. This raises
the important question––is parallel trade good or badfrom an economic point of view?
– why does parallel trade exist in the EU?
Syfait v GlaxoSmithKline AEVE, ECJ, 2008 Following a complaint by a wholesaler, Syfait, to the Greek expressed his opinion that GSK’s conduct infringed competition authority about GSK Greece’s refusal to Article 82 because of the company’s failure to justify its supply Greek wholesalers with three of its patented actions economically. The argument that parallel trade has products (Imigran, Lamictal and Serevent), the Greek negative effects on R&D investments was in principle competition authority initiated an investigation, and accepted, but GSK’s conduct was considered to be subsequently referred several questions to the ECJ. disproportionate. The ruling of the ECJ on September 16th Advocate General Jacobs advised the ECJ in 2004 that the 2008 found that a producer of pharmaceutical products patent holder would not automatically infringe Article 82 must be in a position to protect its own interest if orders (which prohibits abuse of dominance) by refusing to from distributors are out of the ordinary. The court ruled supply because the conduct might be justified in light of that GSK’s actions would constitute an infringement of sector-specific factors. The Advocate General’s advice Article 82 when orders were at ‘ordinary’ levels, but left it motivated the Greek competition authority’s decision in to national courts to ascertain whether the orders in this favour of GSK. At a more recent stage of the legal particular case would be ordinary in relation to the proceedings, in April 2008 Advocate General Colomer requirements of the market.
Sources: Judgment of the Court of Justice in Case C-53/03 Synetairismos Farmakopoion Aitolias & Akarnanias (Syfait) and Others vGlaxoSmithKline plc and Others; Advocate General’s Opinion, Joined cases C-468/06, C-469/06, C-470/06, C-471/06, C-472/06, C-473/06, C-474/06, C-475/06, C-476/06, C-477/06, C-478/06, Advocate General: Ruiz-Jarabo Colomer, April 1st 2008; Advocate General’s Opinion inJoined Cases C-468/06 to C-478/06 Sot. Lélos Kai Sia EE (and Others) v GlaxoSmithKline AEVE, press release 19/08, April 1st 2008;Judgment of the Court (Grand Chamber) (2008), ‘Article 82 EC – Abuse of dominant position – Pharmaceutical products – Refusal to supplywholesalers engaging in parallel exports – Ordinary orders’, in Joined Cases C-468/06 to C-478/06, September 16th. Oxera Agenda October 2008
– why are prices different across Member States?
compensate for the costs of unsuccessful drug
– what are the potential welfare effects arising from
developments. After patent expiry, ‘generic’ entry can
occur and place a competitive constraint on pricing (thiscan raise competition issues in itself, although these are
Why does parallel trade exist in
not the focus here since parallel trade more frequently
Price-setting mechanisms in the pharmaceutical sector
Once a drug is sold, the patent holder can no longer
are different from those in many industries. New drugs
restrict the circulation of the product within the EU. A
brought to the market are afforded patent protection,
buyer of a patent-protected drug is thus entitled to use
which confers a temporary monopoly on its holder
and dispose of it without further restrictions. In the
(historically, this was often for 20 years, although this
terminology of intellectual property law, patent rights are
may differ across jurisdictions and products). Patent
‘exhausted’ within the EU territory. This principle is
holders are thus not constrained by competition when
consistent with the creation of a single European market.
setting prices during this period (they may still be
Parallel trade within the EU would thus appear to be
constrained by national regulations—see below). The
rationale behind patent protection is that there aresufficient incentives to invest in pharmaceutical research,
Wholesale prices for pharmaceutical products have
that the costs of R&D and drug testing are recovered,
traditionally differed within the EU. For example,
and that returns from ‘successful’ drugs are sufficient to
pharmacy purchase prices are on average higher in
Third-degree price discrimination explaining parallel trade Standard economic theory describes third-degree price that consumers in market 1 would pay more and discrimination as a situation where customers are charged consumers in market 2 less. On balance, the welfare different prices for the same product for reasons that are implications of this type of price discrimination cannot be unrelated to costs of production or the quantity sold. The determined at the outset. There is clearly a redistribution market is usually separated by time or location. of income between buyers in the two markets (eg, is it desirable that Greek consumers pay less for their The stylised figure below shows two markets. In market 1, medicines than German ones?). Price discrimination also demand is relatively sensitive to price. Market 2 shows a raises producer surplus at the expense of consumers. market with inelastic demand. With price discrimination, However, the overall welfare effect of this form of monopolists would set prices equal to P1 in market 1 and discrimination from an economic perspective usually P2 in market 2. Prices are thus higher in markets with depends on the following rule of thumb: if total output inelastic demand, despite the marginal costs of production under price discrimination is higher than under uniform being the same. The shaded areas show the respective pricing—ie, if it allows products to reach consumers that producer surpluses (profits) in both markets. would otherwise not be served—then price discrimination Without price discrimination—or where such raises welfare and parallel trade reduces it (eg, in the discrimination is undermined by parallel trade—a extreme, some national markets may not be served if monopolist would charge the same price in both markets. uniform pricing across all countries were required). This The price level would thus be between P1 and P2, implying is ultimately an empirical question. Figure 1 Stylised illustration of third-degree price discrimination with monopoly pricing inal cost 1 inal cost 2 Oxera Agenda October 2008
Germany, the Netherlands and the UK than in Greece
it cannot be ignored that such State intervention
and Spain.3 The national pricing that creates
[price regulation] is one of the factors liable to
opportunities for parallel trade in the European market
create opportunities for parallel trade.6
for pharmaceutical products therefore exhibits thecharacteristics of third-degree price discrimination, the
Parallel imports thus create a tension between the
economic welfare effects of which can be either positive
principle of autonomy of Member States in setting
or negative depending on the circumstances (see the
pharmaceutical prices and the creation of a single
European market. Price differentials in the EU are dueto the Member States each regulating their own
Why are prices different in EU
pharmaceutical prices, while the principle of free
Member States?
movement of goods within the EU allows traders toarbitrage those differences.
An important question is why manufacturers are able tocharge higher prices in some Member States than in
What are the potential welfare
others. Is it due to differences in price elasticity of
effects arising from parallel trade?
demand or willingness to pay, as in the standard theoryof price discrimination? Or is it the result of other
Price reductions for consumers
factors? In the case of pharmaceuticals, wholesale price
Are wholesale price reductions resulting from parallel
differentials for patented drugs mainly reflect differences
trade passed on to end-consumers? Who are the main
in the way countries regulate their pharmaceutical
beneficiaries of those wholesale price reductions?
markets and how prices are determined in negotiations
Answers to these questions require a better
understanding of the different distribution channels inthe pharmaceutical sector.
– Price controls. Member States apply different rules
for fixing wholesale pharmaceutical prices. For
Parallel traders purchase pharmaceutical products from
example, in 2003, unrestrained wholesale pricing of
manufacturers in low-cost countries and sell them to
patented drugs was permitted only in Germany and
pharmacists in countries that offer higher margins.
the UK. Other countries imposed price caps in a
Pharmacists sell those parallel imported drugs to
variety of forms. In Portugal, for example, minimum
end-consumers, who are then fully or partly reimbursed
prices were set at the level of identical products in
by health insurance. Health insurances are either
publicly or privately financed, implying that the end-consumer and tax payer indirectly benefit from cost
– Reimbursement systems. Insurers have incentives
to reduce overall expenditures on pharmaceuticalproducts by limiting reimbursed services. The design
A study by the London School of Economics (LSE)
of reimbursement systems differs across Member
examines the effect of parallel trade in the Netherlands,
States. For example, under the German reference
Germany, the UK, Norway, Sweden and Denmark, the
pricing system, the patient has to pay any amount in
main destination countries for parallel trade in the EU.
excess of the maximum reimbursement price set by
The study shows the extent of benefits arising due to
the government.5 A co-payment mechanism requires
parallel trade for parallel traders, pharmacies and health
the patient to make some of the payments regardless
– Parallel traders. As shown in Table 1 below, the extra
– Negotiations. National health and social insurance
profits made by parallel traders are considerably
programmes are often ultimately controlled by the
larger than the cost savings made by health insurance
government. As a sole purchaser of pharmaceutical
organisations and pharmacies.7 Parallel trade
products, governments have a strong bargaining
therefore causes a redistribution of profits from
position to negotiate prices with patent holders.
manufacturers to intermediaries. A change in the
Wholesale price differentials may therefore also reflect
profitability of the different parties in the upstream
country-specific policy objectives towards pricing of
segment of the value chain could alter the incentives
pharmaceuticals and profitability of pharmaceutical
faced by the different parties. As a result, there may
be a positive effect on investments in distributionsystems but a marginal reduction in R&D spending by
The importance of regulatory restrictions on pricing
increasing opportunities for parallel trade has also beenacknowledged in the recent judgment of the ECJ inrelation to the GSK Greece case:
Oxera Agenda October 2008 Benefits of parallel trade to parallel traders, pharmacies and health insurances, 2002
Notes: 1 Revenues and profits to parallel importers are calculated as the inter-price difference multiplied by the volume of parallel imports inthe destination country. 2 Benefits to pharmacies are estimated on the basis of the intra-country price spread between locally sourced andparallel imported drugs multiplied by the quantity of parallel imports sold. The effect on pharmacies excludes discount. 3 Savings to healthinsurance are calculated as the sum of direct cost savings due to the intra-country price spread and competition effects. Competition effects indestination countries describe the extent to which there is price competition and price convergence over time. 4 ‘Clawback’ refers to asituation where pharmacies have to share discounts received by suppliers with health insurances. Pharmacies are reimbursed at the list priceminus the clawback, which is usually expressed as a percentage of the price. Source: London School of Economics (2004), ‘The Economic Impact of Pharmaceutical Parallel Trade in European Union Member States: AStakeholder Analysis’, Special Research Paper.
– Pharmacies. Benefits to pharmacies are relatively
only the transactions costs and extra capital expenditure
for setting up the distribution network.
– Health insurance schemes. Table 1 also outlines Efficiency gains
cost savings for health insurance systems. Parallel
Efficiency gains in production are another potential
imported drugs are sold at a lower price to the
source of benefits of parallel trade. Those benefits could
end-consumer, which reduces the costs to health
potentially accrue in a situation of international arbitrage.
insurance systems. Cost savings to health insurance
However, this is less likely to arise in the pharmaceutical
systems are likely to be passed on to tax payers
sector. The reason for this is that prices in exporting
countries are not lower because of more efficientproducers, but because of different regulatory
– End-consumers. Direct benefits for patients from
approaches to pricing. Parallel trade therefore does not
parallel trade depend on the structure of cost-sharing
appear to promote efficiency gains in production in the
systems in the respective countries. In co-payment
usual way of placing pressure on costs. In fact, it could
systems, customers contribute to total healthcare
increase real social costs as additional transportation
expenditure by making a small payment. Parallel trade
Shortage of supply in the exporting country
The overall finding of the LSE study is that the
Another potential effect besides possible price reductions
pass-through rate of wholesale price reductions to
is a shortage in supply in the source country.11
end-consumers is relatively low. Parallel traders are
Pharmaceutical companies are required to supply all EU
shown to maximise their profits by placing parallel
Member States, whereas parallel importers serve only
imported products on the market at a slightly lower price
those countries offering attractive profit margins. In low-
than the locally sourced product. In the GSK Greece
price countries, manufacturers may sell part of their
case, the ECJ also found that a large proportion of the
goods to parallel traders which export the goods to other
price differential is taken up by intermediaries.9
countries. Demand in low-price countries might thereforenot be met even though manufacturers fulfil their
An interesting question is whether the high proportion of
requirements. Demand in the exporting country may not
benefits accruing to the traders reflects some degree of
be met in full if parallel traders find it more profitable to
market power. A potential reason for such market power
sell drugs abroad than in the source country. That
could be caps on the amounts which can be exported.
parallel imports may therefore lead to shortages in
An alternative explanation could be that the margin
exporting countries was also found by the ECJ.12
earned by the parallel importer is a normal profit,
Reduction in manufacturers’ marginal
representing the set-up of the trading and distribution
investment incentives into R&D
network. In the latter case, the size of the regulatory
An important question yet to be explored in the economic
differences creates just enough arbitrage opportunity to
literature is to what extent a limitation of parallel trade
generate trading opportunities, but it is sufficient to cover
would increase future R&D investment, if at all. Sunk
Oxera Agenda October 2008
investment in R&D forms a significant part of
levels. This problem is not unique to the pharmaceutical
pharmaceutical companies’ overall costs. R&D is a form
sector. So is it necessary to create sector-specific
of joint cost incurred by pharmaceutical companies that
competition rules for dealing with parallel trade in this
operate globally, such that these costs cannot easily be
sector? Can we find a solution with the help of
attributed to a particular country. Parallel imports reduce
the profits of manufacturers in high-cost countries, which,in turn, may limit manufacturers’ marginal ability to
The welfare effects of parallel trade are ambiguous. On
the one hand, it reduces prices for drugs in high-costcountries. On the other, it may create a shortage in
Conclusion
supply in the exporting country and reduce marginal
At the heart of the policy debate surrounding parallel
investment incentives of manufacturers. The recent ECJ
trade in drugs lies the peculiarity that the principle of a
judgment tries to strike the right balance by allowing
single European Market strives towards uniform price
refusal to supply wholesalers/traders whose demand is
levels, while Member States regulate prices at different
out of the ‘ordinary’. This debate is likely to continue.
Oxera Economics Council, September 15th 2008 These issues, along with others relating to the and Statistics (ECARES), Université Libre de Bruxelles; pharmaceutical industry, were discussed during the Estelle Cantillon, Université Libre de Bruxelles; Eric van second Oxera Economics Council meeting in Brussels on Damme, Tilburg University; Jordi Gual, Caixa d’Estalvis i September 15th. The Council seeks to provide economic Pensions de Barcelona and IESE Business School, insight into challenging issues faced by governments, Barcelona; Bruno Jullien, Toulouse School of Economics; regulators and business in the context of public policy in Patrick Legros, ECARES, Université Libre de Bruxelles; competition and regulation. Massimo Motta, European University Institute, Florence; and by two guest participants, Pat Treacy, Partner, At the meeting, Oxera economists were joined by fellow Bristows, and Vincent Verouden, Chief Economist Team, Council members Mathias Dewatripont, Chairman, DG Competition. European Center for Advanced Research in Economics See www.oxera.com for more information.
1 EFPIA (2008), ‘The Pharmaceutical Industry in Figures’, European Federation of Pharmaceutical Industries and Associations, p. 3. 2 Ganslandt, M. and Maskus, K.E. (2004), ‘Parallel imports and the Pricing of Pharmaceutical Products: Evidence from the European Union’, Journal of Health Economics, 23, March 17th, pp. 1035–57. 3 This was confirmed by a price comparison of 19 pharmaceutical products in 14 European countries undertaken by the London School of Economics. London School of Economics (2004), ‘The Economic Impact of Pharmaceutical Parallel Trade in European Union Member States: A Stakeholder Analysis’, Special Research Paper, January, Table 3.2. 4 Mrazek, M. and Mossialos, E. (2004), ‘Regulating Pharmaceutical Prices in the European Union’, in Regulating Pharmaceuticals in Europe: Striving for Efficiency, Equity and Quality, Maidenhead: Open University Press, pp. 114–29. 5 OHE Consulting (2005), ‘The Many Faces of Innovation’, February 18th. 6 Judgment of the Court (Grand Chamber) (2008), Article 82 EC – Abuse of dominant position – Pharmaceutical products – Refusal to supply wholesalers engaging in parallel exports – Ordinary orders, In Joined Cases C-468/06 to C-478/06, September 16th, recital 67. 7 London School of Economics (2004), op. cit., p.15. 8 Ibid. p. 58. 9 Judgment of the Court (Grand Chamber) (2008), Article 82 EC – Abuse of dominant position – Pharmaceutical products – Refusal to supply wholesalers engaging in parallel exports – Ordinary orders, In Joined Cases C-468/06 to C-478/06, September 16th, recital 54. 10 Danzon, P. (1997), ‘Price Discrimination for Pharmaceuticals: Welfare Effects in the US and the EU’, International Journal of the Economics of Business, 4:3, pp. 301–21. 11 Kanavos, P.G. and Costa-Font, J. (2005), ‘Pharmaceutical Parallel Trade in Europe: Stakeholder and Competition Effects’, Economic Policy, 20:44, October, pp. 751–98. 12 Judgment of the Court (Grand Chamber) (2008), Article 82 EC – Abuse of dominant position – Pharmaceutical products – Refusal to supply wholesalers engaging in parallel exports – Ordinary orders, In Joined Cases C-468/06 to C-478/06, September 16th, recital 43.
Oxera, 2008. All rights reserved. Except for the quotation of short passages for the purposes of criticism or review, no part may beused or reproduced without permission. Oxera Agenda October 2008 If you have any questions regarding the issues raised in this article, please contact the editor, Derek Holt: tel +44 (0) 1865 253 000 or email d_holt@oxera.com Other articles in the October issue of Agenda include: state aid and the banking crisis time and timing in capital markets: implications for pensions investment what we talk about when we talk about consumer welfare Phil Evans, FIPRA For details of how to subscribe to Agenda, please email agenda@oxera.com, or visit our website Oxera Agenda October 2008
Waukee Family YMCA Rays Swim Team Winter 2007-2008 TOP TIMES for Short Course Yards GIRLS 8&UN 25 FREE GIRLS 9-10 100 FREE GIRLS 8&UN 25 BREAST GIRLS 9-10 50 BACK GIRLS 8&UN 50 BREAST GIRLS 8&UN 50 FREE GIRLS 9-10 100 BACK GIRLS 8&UN 25 FLY GIRLS 9-10 50 BREAST GIRLS 8&UN 100 I.M. GIRLS 8&UN 25 BACK GIRLS 9-10 50 FREE GIR
for centuries are still central to the national identity of we shall be opening a Europe House in Ashgabat. modern-day Turkmens. You can clearly recognize this A further stimulus to our relations is the enormous in our government’s foreign policy based on the prin-potential the EU has in economics and trade, fi nance ciple of positive neutrality, which has been followed and investment,